28) South Seas Bubble of 1720: the First Major Manipulation of Financial Markets
Notes for Economics
www.saseassociates.com
Next, we will look at the British crisis known
as the South Seas Bubble, a crisis that stands
as the first major manipulation of financial
markets. Until the Crash of 1929, this bubble
endured as the classic example of opportunistic
self-enhancement.
The South Seas Company was formed by Parliament
as a British trade concession in 1711. This
was a monopoly for areas of the Pacific that
were under British rule. The company was a
startup firm with no sales and no earnings,
only with great prospects. The real prospects
centered on market manipulation and insider
trading.
In the early eighteenth century, Britain had
entered its period of imperial prosperity.
However, stock ownership remained a matter
of privilege that was limited mostly to the
aristocracy. Furthermore, women could not
inherit land, although females could own stock
at that time. A pent-up demand for stock developed
because of wide accessibility along with the
added benefit that dividends that were paid
out of profits went untaxed.
Parliament granted the enterprise a monopoly
concession along with loaned capitalization
of ₤10 million pounds sterling. Publicly
unknown at the time, members of Parliament
had bought capitalization bonds for South
Seas at ₤55. Once the company went public,
these investors exchanged each unit for ₤100
of stock in the South Seas Company.
However, its inexperienced directors quickly
entered into the slave trade, a venture at
which they failed. South Seas maintained its
stock price in the market despite this misfortune
as well as a war with Spain, shipments of
goods that were misrouted and lost, and bonuses
paid to the directors in a form that diluted
the value of shares.
Nevertheless, the situation improved in 1719.
Britain signed the Peace of Utrecht, a treaty
with Spain that enabled British trade with
Mexico. Given this newfound prosperity, the
directors of South Seas offered to fund the
entire British national debt of ₤31 million.
Stock prices doubled.
Five days after the bill became law, South
Seas offered a new issue of stock at ₤300
per share. The company offered a second issue
at ₤400. This one rose to ₤550 per share
within a month. The directors offered yet
another at 10% down, with no payments for
one year. Share price continued to rise to
₤1,000. The feasibility of the scheme became
secondary as the Greater-Fool Theory took
over—speculators would purchase shares,
prices would rise, secondary buyers would
appear, and the speculators would profit in
the after-market.
In the summer of 1720, the directors liquidated
their own shares. The news of their divestiture
leaked out quickly. Share price collapsed
and a market panic ensued. The British government
narrowly averted the complete erosion of public
credit. In response to this threat, Parliament
passed the Bubble Act that forbade issuance
of stock certificates in any company.
In addition, Britain implemented other measures
in order to restore confidence. The government
confiscated the estates of company directors
in an attempt to remunerate South Seas Company
investors. Other propositions put forth in
Parliament included placing bankers in sacks
filled with snakes and throwing them into
the Thames River!
In summarizing this bubble, let us analyze
the events. First, there was a pent-up demand
for investment opportunities. Second, the
government sponsored a trade-concession monopoly.
Third, inexperienced management failed to
create any real value for the company. Fourth,
war and the entry of new competition exerted
external pressures on the firm. Fifth, graft
occurred, which involved members of Parliament
in an effort to pass legislation that was
advantageous to a private company. Sixth,
dilutive stock dividends and new (dilutive)
stock issues were sold on generous terms and
margins while insiders manipulated trading
that included the dumping of shares.
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=rfZ4OZNhAJ8